Tuesday, April 2, 2013

Why this kolaveri over current account deficit


Why this kolaveri over current account deficit

Current account has conspicuously emerged as one of the primary concerns in past couple of months. Everyone – Government, RBI, investors, analysts, economists and financial institutions – seems extremely concerned about the current account deficit. The other deficits – fiscal, governance, trust, energy, infrastructure et. al. have taken a back seat for the time being.

In our view, the concern over high current account deficit, though not completely unwarranted, may be slightly misplaced. We worry that more than due emphasis on the problem may lead to desperate solutions leading to introduction of some structural imbalances in the economy, e.g., RBI postponing the replenishing of forex reserves, unwillingly liberalizing FII debt investment rules, enhancing export subsidies, etc.

Following the oil price shocks in the 1970s, there have been large swings in the current account balances of most countries. Australia, New Zealand, Portugal and the US have been running large current account deficits for the most part of the 1990s. At the end of 2000, the US current account deficit had reached to $415.5 billion, equivalent to 4.5 percent of US GDP. There is enough empirical evidence to suggest that while some countries such as Ireland, Australia, Israel, Malaysia and South Korea were able to sustain large current account deficits for many years, other countries such as Chile and Mexico suffered severe losses. Excessive current account deficits in crisis countries were also a prevalent feature of the 1997 Asian crisis.
Current account measures trade, international income, direct transfers of capital, and investment income made on assets. A current account deficit is when a country's government, businesses and individuals import more goods, services and capital than hey export.

The current account by definition should correct itself in due course. For example - the fall in currency value, a natural outcome of high CAD, should normally result in rise in the value of foreign and gold reserves of the country; it should make the exports competitive and destroy the demand for inflated imports if CAD persists for longer period; the high yield on currency should attract more capital resulting in higher investment, employment and savings rate resulting in creation of additional local capacities leading to import substitution.
However, artificial curbs like capital controls, managing the currency value at artificially higher level, and forced import substitution and subsidization, may introduce structural imbalances in the economy that may take longer to correct.

Given that the Indian currency is mostly convertible on trade account now (this was not the case during Asian crisis of 1990s) we need to be little more cautious. But interfering with market forces will only exacerbate the problem.

We continue to suggest a short trade on INR, with the expectation of a 7-10% fall in next 6-9 months.

No comments:

Post a Comment